The Tariff Labyrinth: Finding Adridne’s Thread in a Maze of Global Duties

Zac Kienzle

|
July 28, 2025

Recent U.S. protectionist policies provide a stark, real-world test of long-standing economic theory. This paper reveals that despite theoretical debates, these modern tariffs have imposed net economic costs, primarily by disrupting global value chains and leading to substantial welfare losses. The empirical results from this period challenge the efficacy of protectionism in a deeply interconnected global economy.

Tariff Mechanism

Tariffs, taxes levied on imported goods, have long been a pivotal instrument in economic policy, shaping international trade dynamics and domestic industrial landscapes. Their application is multifaceted, extending from the historical primary role of generating governmental revenue to contemporary uses in protecting nascent domestic industries, addressing trade imbalances, and serving as a tool in international diplomacy and strategic competition (Irwin, 2017; Schaffer, 2018). This paper will examine the mechanisms and theories behind tariff policy, assess the empirical evidence of their impact in a world of global value chains, and analyze the recent U.S. shift towards protectionism as a critical case study.

Tariffs manifest in several principal forms, each with distinct economic implications. Ad valorem tariffs are levied as a percentage of the imported good's monetary value, making their impact sensitive to price fluctuations. Specific tariffs are a fixed sum charged per physical unit of an imported good (e.g., per ton, per item), offering more predictable protection when import prices are volatile but potentially becoming less restrictive with inflation. Compound tariffs merge ad valorem and specific components, often applied to goods where value and quantity are relevant considerations.

Building on these basic types, a related and significant protectionist strategy is tariff escalation, involving progressively higher import duties on goods as they move up the value chain from raw materials to semi-processed inputs and finally to finished products (Khasnobis, 2004). The explicit aim is to shield domestic processing and manufacturing sectors by making imported raw materials relatively cheap while discouraging the import of finished goods, thereby emboldening domestic value-creation processes. However, this can also lead to inefficiencies in the protected sectors and higher costs for consumers of final goods (OECD, 2002).

Understanding these mechanisms is key to interpreting their use throughout history. Historically, global tariff policy has oscillated between prevailing protectionist impulses and periods of concerted trade liberalisation. The mercantilist era, roughly the 16th to 18th centuries, favoured high tariffs and other trade barriers to ensure positive trade balances, viewing wealth as finite and international trade as a zero-sum game (LaHaye, 2017). The subsequent Industrial Revolution saw a more nuanced application, with nations like Britain initially using tariffs to nurture emerging industries before championing free trade once their dominance was established (Chang, 2002).

A stark example of protectionism's potential perils is the U.S. Smoot-Hawley Tariff Act of 1930, wherein the enacted policies significantly raised duties on thousands of imported items. Contextually, it aimed to protect the U.S. agricultural industry and its constituents from foreign competition. However, it triggered widespread global retaliation, leading to a drastic contraction in international trade and significantly deepening the Great Depression (Eichengreen, 1986; Irwin, 1996). In direct response to the devastating consequences of this era, a post-World War II consensus towards multilateral trade liberalisation was fostered. This movement was primarily spearheaded by the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT), established in 1947, and its successor, the World Trade Organisation (WTO), formed in 1995. These institutions, operating on core principles such as Most-Favoured-Nation (MFN) treatment (requiring non-discrimination between trading partners) and National Treatment (treating imported and locally-produced goods equally once they enter the market), facilitated substantial and progressive global tariff reductions over several decades (Bagwell & Staiger, 2001). However, recent years, particularly marked by the policies under the Trump administration in the United States, have signalled a notable resurgence in protectionist sentiment and unilateral tariff actions, challenging the established multilateral framework (Bown & Kolb, 2021; Fajgelbaum et al., 2020).

This rules-based system, designed specifically to prevent the trade wars of the past, forms the critical backdrop for understanding the 21st-century return to protectionism. The recent U.S. policy shift did not merely represent a change in tariff rates; it posed a fundamental challenge to the post-war economic order itself.

A Paradigm Shift in U.S. Tariffs

The administration of President Donald Trump initiated a significant departure from decades of U.S. trade policy that had favoured mainly multilateral liberalisation and tariff reduction. This shift was defined by a preference for unilateral actions, bilateral negotiations backed by tariff threats, and justifications based on national security and perceived unfair trade practices by other nations.

In March 2018, the U.S. imposed tariffs of 25% on steel and 10% on aluminium imports from most countries, citing national security concerns under Section 232 of the Trade Expansion Act of 1962. Many economists and trading partners met this rationale with scepticism and viewed it as a misuse of the national security provision (Linciome et al., 2021). Moreover, beginning in July 2018 and escalating through 2019, the U.S. levied tariffs on a substantial portion of imports from China, eventually covering goods worth hundreds of billions of dollars. These tariffs, imposed under Section 301 of the Trade Act of 1974, targeted alleged unfair trade practices by China, including intellectual property theft and forced technology transfer.

The economic impacts of these tariffs have been extensively studied. A consistent finding across multiple analyses is that the costs of these tariffs were largely passed through to U.S. consumers and firms in the form of higher prices, leading to real income losses (Amiti, Redding, and Weinstein, 2019; Fajgelbaum et al., 2020; Cavallo et al., 2021). Contextually, Fajgelbaum et al. (2020) estimated that the tariffs resulted in an annual deadweight loss of approximately $16.8 billion and a real income loss of around $51 billion for U.S. consumers when accounting for tariff revenue.

Employment effects were generally found to be minimal or even negative, particularly when considering retaliatory tariffs. While some protected sub-sectors in steel might have seen small gains, these were often offset by job losses in manufacturing sectors that use steel and aluminium as inputs (due to higher costs) and in agriculture, which faced significant retaliatory tariffs from China and other countries (Flaaen, Hortaçsu, and Tintelnot, 2020; Fetzer & Schwarz, 2021). Supply chains were significantly disrupted, forcing businesses to scramble for alternative sources or absorb higher costs, creating considerable uncertainty that dampened investment (Handley, Kamal, and Monarch, 2020; Bloom et al., 2018, on general policy uncertainty). Despite the aim of reducing the U.S. trade deficit, particularly with China, the overall U.S. trade deficit widened during this period. However, bilateral deficits with China did see some reduction, often offset by increased deficits with other nations as trade patterns shifted. These actions did not occur in a vacuum; rather, they represent the latest chapter in a sharp and long-standing theoretical divide over the economic rationale for tariffs.

Theoretical Framework

The economic rationale concerning tariffs is sharplydivided, with robust arguments supporting free trade and protectionism.

The Case for Free Trade

The classical case for free trade is built mainly upon Adam Smith's (1776) concept of absolute advantage, where nations benefit by specialising in goods they can produce more efficiently than others. This was refined by David Ricardo's (1817) theory of comparative advantage, which posits that mutual gains from trade arise if nations specialise in producing goods with a lower relative opportunity cost, even if they lack an absolute advantage in any good. This specialisation, followed by international trade, enhances global productive efficiency and overall welfare. The Heckscher-Ohlin model further developed this by suggesting that comparative advantage stems from differences in national factor endowments (e.g., capital, labour, land), predicting that countries will export goods that make intensive use of their abundant factors (Heckscher & Ohlin, 1993). These foundational theories generally conclude that tariffs, by distorting relative prices and interfering with specialisation, impede global efficiency, reduce overall output, and diminish aggregate welfare.

Justifications for Protectionism

Conversely, various protectionist arguments offer justifications for the imposition of tariffs. The infant industry argument, prominently articulated by Alexander Hamilton (1791) in his "Report on Manufactures" and later by Friedrich List (1841) in "The National System of Political Economy," suggests that new domestic industries, particularly in developing countries, may require temporary protection from established international competitors to achieve economies of scale, learn by doing, and become internationally competitive. Hamilton advocated this strategy for the nascent industrialisation of the United States. Simultaneously, List famously accused Britain of "kicking away the ladder" by promoting global free trade only after its industries had matured behind protective barriers (Chang, 2002). However, this argument faces significant criticism, as governments have notable informational challenges in "picking winners"—identifying industries with genuine potential for future competitiveness (Baldwin et al., 2015). Moreover, protected industries often develop a political reliance on continued protection, lobbying against its removal and potentially remaining inefficient indefinitely (Krueger, 1988). An empirical study of the 19th-century U.S. tinplate industry, often cited as a successful case of infant industry protection, found that while protection did accelerate the industry's development, it ultimately failed a social cost-benefit test due to the high costs imposed on consumers (Irwin, 1998).

The optimal tariff theory has early conceptual origins in the work of Robert Torrens and John Stuart Mill and was later formalised by economists such as F.Y. Edgeworth and Nicholas Kaldor (1940). It posits that a large country possessing significant market power (monopsony power in import markets) can improve its terms of trade by imposing a tariff. By restricting import demand, the large country can compel foreign exporters to lower their pre-tariff prices, effectively shifting part of the tariff burden onto them and increasing the importing country's welfare (Broda et al., 2008). However, this theory is heavily criticised for several reasons. Firstly, it assumes the absence of retaliation from trading partners—a highly unrealistic scenario in the modern global economy, where retaliatory tariffs can quickly erode any initial terms-of-trade gains and lead to mutually damaging trade wars (Johnson, 1953). Secondly, the practical difficulty of accurately calculating the "optimal" tariff rate, which depends on complex export supply elasticities, is immense. Thirdly, even if successful for one country, it reduces global welfare, making it a "beggar-thy-neighbour" policy (Irwin, 2017).

Empirics

While theoretical arguments provide the rationale for tariff policy, empirical research reveals its real-world consequences. A vast body of empirical research largely indicates that tariffs, especially when broadly applied or met with retaliation, impose net economic costs. They typically lead to higher domestic prices for both the directly taxed imported goods and their domestic substitutes, as foreign exporters attempt to pass on tariff costs and domestic producers exploit the reduced competitive pressure to raise their prices (Amiti, Redding, and Weinstein, 2019; De Loecker et al., 2016). This price increase directly reduces consumer purchasing power and erodes real wages. Furthermore, tariffs can limit product variety available to consumers and intermediate inputs available to firms, stifling innovation and productivity (Goldberg et al., 2010).

Macroeconomically, sustained periods of tariff increases are generally associated with declines in real GDP and slower economic growth. For instance, research analysing historical trade liberalisations often finds positive impacts on growth (Estevadeordal & Taylor, 2013; Wacziarg & Welch, 2008), suggesting symmetrically that tariff increases would have deleterious effects. Recent studies on the U.S. tariffs imposed from 2018 onwards provide a powerful modern example of these effects, confirming significant pass-through of tariff costs to U.S. importers and, ultimately, consumers, with little evidence of foreign exporters absorbing these costs by lowering their prices (Fajgelbaum et al., 2020; Amiti, Redding, and Weinstein, 2019).

The Challenge of Global Value Chains (GVCs)

The rise of global value chains (GVCs) over the past few decades has added complexity to analysing tariff impacts. GVCs describe the phenomenon where different stages of the production process for a single good or service are located across different countries, with components and services crossing borders multiple times before the final product reaches the consumer (Antràs & Chor, 2022; Hummels, Ishii, and Yi, 2001). This international fragmentation of production has allowed firms to optimise costs and leverage specialised expertise globally.

Tariffs can be particularly damaging in a world characterised by GVCs for several reasons. When intermediate inputs cross borders multiple times, tariffs can be levied at successive stages of production. This so-called "compounding effect" means that the total tariff burden on a final good can be substantially higher than the nominal tariff rate on that good itself, as tariffs are paid on already tariff-laden components (Yi, 2003). This significantly increases production costs for firms reliant on GVCs. Moreover, GVCs are built on intricate networks of suppliers and producers.

Moreover, GVCs are built on intricate networks of suppliers and producers. Tariffs can render previously efficient GVC linkages uneconomical, forcing firms to search for alternative suppliers or reconfigure their entire production networks—a costly and disruptive process. This process of adjustment is often slow and uncertain and can involve significant write-offs of relationship-specific investments (Baldwin & Lopez-Gonzalez, 2015). Firms that use imported inputs to produce goods for export (a common feature of GVC participation) are hit twice by tariffs on intermediates. Their input costs rise, making their final products less competitive in global markets. This is particularly problematic for developing countries seeking to integrate into GVCs as a pathway to industrialisation (Koopman, Wang, and Wei, 2014).

Imposing tariffs, especially if unpredictable or part of a broader trend towards protectionism, creates significant policy uncertainty. This uncertainty can deter firms from long-term investments in GVCs as the future cost and accessibility of critical inputs and export market access become precarious (Handley & Limão, 2017).

Bibliography

Agricultural Policies in OECD Countries 2002 [WWW Document], 2002. OECD. URL https://www.oecd.org/en/publications/agricultural-policies-in-oecd-countries-2002_agr_oecd-2002-en.html (accessed 5.25.25).

Amiti, M., Redding, S.J., Weinstein, D.E., 2019. The Impact of the 2018 Tariffs on Prices and Welfare. Journal of Economic Perspectives 33, 187–210. https://doi.org/10.1257/jep.33.4.187

Antràs, P., Chor, D., 2022. Global value chains, in: Handbook of International Economics. Elsevier, pp. 297–376. https://doi.org/10.1016/bs.hesint.2022.02.005

Bagwell, K., Staiger, R., 2001. National sovereignty in the world trading system. Harvard International Review 22, 54–59.

Baldwin, R., Lopez-Gonzalez, J., 2015. Supply-chain Trade: A Portrait of Global Patterns and Several Testable Hypotheses. The World Economy 38, 1682–1721. https://doi.org/10.1111/twec.12189

Baldwin, R.E., 1969. The Case against Infant-Industry Tariff Protection. Journal of Political Economy 77, 295–305. https://doi.org/10.1086/259517

Bown, C.P., 2021. The US–China trade war and Phase One agreement. Journal of Policy Modeling, The World Economy After Covid-19 43, 805–843. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jpolmod.2021.02.009

Broda, C., Limao, N., Weinstein, D.E., 2008. Optimal Tariffs and Market Power: The Evidence. American Economic Review 98, 2032–2065. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.98.5.2032

Cavallo, A., Gopinath, G., Neiman, B., Tang, J., 2021. Tariff Pass-Through at the Border and at the Store: Evidence from US Trade Policy. American Economic Review: Insights 3, 19–34. https://doi.org/10.1257/aeri.20190536

Costinot, A., Rodríguez-Clare, A., 2014. Chapter 4 - Trade Theory with Numbers: Quantifying the Consequences of Globalization, in: Gopinath, G., Helpman, E., Rogoff, K. (Eds.), Handbook of International Economics, Handbook of International Economics. Elsevier, pp. 197–261. https://doi.org/10.1016/B978-0-444-54314-1.00004-5

De Loecker, J., Goldberg, P.K., Khandelwal, A.K., Pavcnik, N., 2016. Prices, Markups, and Trade Reform. Econometrica 84, 445–510. https://doi.org/10.3982/ECTA11042

Eichengreen, B., 1986. The Political Economy of the Smoot-Hawley Tariff. Working Paper Series. https://doi.org/10.3386/w2001

Estevadeordal, A., Taylor, A.M., 2013. Is the Washington Consensus Dead? Growth, Openness, and the Great Liberalization, 1970s-2000s. The Review of Economics and Statistics 95, 1669–1690.

Fajgelbaum, P.D., Goldberg, P.K., Kennedy, P.J., Khandelwal, A.K., 2020. The Return to Protectionism*. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 135, 1–55. https://doi.org/10.1093/qje/qjz036

Fetzer, T., Schwarz, C., 2021. Tariffs and Politics: Evidence from Trump’s Trade Wars. The Economic Journal 131, 1717–1741. https://doi.org/10.1093/ej/ueaa122

Gelles, J.-D., 2002. CHANG, Ha-Joon. Kicking A way The Ladder: Development Strategy in Hístorical Perspective. Londres: Anthem Press, 2002. Economia 25, 229–231. https://doi.org/10.18800/economia.200202.007

Goldberg, P., Khandelwal, A., Pavcnik, N., Topalova, P.B., 2010. Imported Intermediate Inputs and Domestic Product Growth: Evidence from India.

Guha-Khasnobis, B., 2004. Who Gains From Tariff Escalation? Journal of Economic Integration 19, 416–425.

Handley, K., Limão, N., 2017. Policy Uncertainty, Trade, and Welfare: Theory and Evidence for China and the United States. The American Economic Review 107, 2731–2783.

Hummels, D., Ishii, J., Yi, K.-M., 2001. The nature and growth of vertical specialization in world trade. Journal of International Economics, Trade and Wages 54, 75–96. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0022-1996(00)00093-3

Irwin, D.A., 1996. The Smoot-Hawley Tariff: A Quantitative Assessment.

Irwin, D.A., 1998. Did Late Nineteenth Century U.S. Tariffs Promote Infant Industries? Evidence from the Tinplate Industry.

Irwin, D.A., 2017. Introduction to “Clashing over Commerce: A History of US Trade Policy.” NBER Chapters 1–27.

Johnson, H.G., 1953. Optimum Tariffs and Retaliation. The Review of Economic Studies 21, 142–153. https://doi.org/10.2307/2296006

Jones, R.W., 1993. Heckscher-Ohlin trade theory: Harry Flam and M. June Flanders, eds., (The MIT Press, Cambridge, MA, 1991) pp. x + 222. Journal of International Economics 35, 197–199.

Koopman, R., Wang, Z., Wei, S.-J., 2014. Tracing Value-Added and Double Counting in Gross Exports. The American Economic Review 104, 459–494.

Krueger, A.O., 1988. The Political Economy of Controls: American Sugar. Working Paper Series. https://doi.org/10.3386/w2504

LaHaye, L., 2017. Mercantilism, in: The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics. Palgrave Macmillan UK, London, pp. 1–4. https://doi.org/10.1057/978-1-349-95121-5_838-2

Protectionism or National Security? The Use and Abuse of Section 232 [WWW Document], 2021. . Cato Institute. URL https://www.cato.org/policy-analysis/protectionism-or-national-security-use-abuse-section-232 (accessed 5.25.25).

Shaffer, G., 2018. A Tragedy in the Making? The Decline of Law and the Return of Power in International Trade Relations.

Wacziarg, R., Welch, K.H., 2008. Trade Liberalization and Growth: New Evidence. The World Bank Economic Review 22, 187–231. https://doi.org/10.1093/wber/lhn007

Yi, K.-M., 2003. Can Vertical Specialization Explain the Growth of World Trade? Journal of Political Economy 111, 52–102. https://doi.org/10.1086/344805

Head back to blogs